1.
Hinnosaar, T. (2024).
Price Setting on a Network
.
RAND Journal of Economics
,
I study price setting within a network of interconnected monopolists. Some firms possess stronger commitment or bargaining power than others, enabling them to influence the pricing decisions of other firms. While it is well-understood that multiple marginalization reduces both total profits and social welfare, I show that strategic interactions within the network exacerbate the marginalization problem. Individual profits are proportional to a new measure of network centrality, defined by the equilibrium characterization. The results underscore the importance of network structure in policy considerations, such as mergers or trade policies.
2.
Acemoglu, D., & Jensen, M. K. (2024).
Equilibrium Analysis in Behavioural One-Sector Growth Models
.
Review of Economic Studies
, 91(2), 599-640. https://doi.org/10.1093/restud/rdad043
Rich behavioral biases, mistakes and limits on rational decision-making are often thought to make equilibrium analysis much more intractable. We establish that this is not the case in the context of one-sector growth models such as Ramsey-Cass-Koopmans or Bewley-Aiyagari models. We break down the response of the economy to a change in the environment or policy into two parts: the direct response at the given (pre-tax) prices, and the equilibrium response which plays out as prices change. Our main result demonstrates that under weak regularity conditions, regardless of the details of behavioral preferences, mistakes and constraints on decision-making, the long-run equilibrium will involve a greater capital-labor ratio if and only if the direct response (from the corresponding consumption-saving model) involves an increase in aggregate savings. One implication of this result is that, from a qualitative point of view, behavioral biases matter for long-run equilibrium if and only if they change the direction of the direct response. We provide detailed illustrations of how this result can be applied and generates new insights using models of misperceptions, self-control and temptation, and naive and sophisticated quasi-hyperbolic discounting.
3.
Jensen, M. K., & Luo, R. (2024).
The plague, the skill-premium, and the road to modern economic growth
. Macroeconomic Dynamics, https://doi.org/10.1017/S1365100523000573
4.
Bougheas, S., Harvey, D. I., Kirman, A., & Nelson, D. (2024).
Systemic Risk in Banking, Fire Sales, and Macroeconomic Disasters
.
Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control
,
We develop a dynamic computational network model of the banking system where fire sales provide the amplification mechanism of financial shocks. Each period a finite number of banks offers a large, but finite, number of loans to households. Banks with excess liquidity also offer loans to other banks with insufficient liquidity. Thus, each period an interbank loan market is endogenously formed. Bank assets are hit by idiosyncratic shocks drawn from a thin tailed distribution. The uneven distribution of shocks across banks implies that each period there are banks that become insolvent. If insolvent banks happen also to be heavily indebted to other banks, their liquidation can trigger other bank failures. We find that the distribution across time of the growth rate of banking assets has a ‘fat left tail’ that corresponds to rare economic disasters. We also find that the distribution of initial shocks is not a perfect predictor of economic activity; that is some of the uncertainty is endogenous and related to the structure of the interbank network.
5.
Albornoz, F., Bottan, N., Cruces, G., Hoffmann, B., Torcuato, U., & Tella, D. (2024).
Backlash Against Expert Recommendations: Reactions to COVID-19 Advice in Latin America
.
Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization
,
Public adherence with health recommendations is vital for effective crisis response. During the COVID-19 pandemic, governments faced considerable challenges in persuading the public to adopt new recommendations. Using large-scale survey experiments across 12 Latin American countries, we investigate how respondents' agreement with health recommendations is affected by their attribution to experts from different sectors. Our results uncover a robust backlash against experts for pandemic-specific recommendations, but not for more general health advice. The backlash does not depend on the type of expert (academic, public or private sector). Our experimental setup allows us to concurrently assess the significance of different factors behind these results. Anti-intellectualism plays a role, since individuals with low initial trust in experts exhibit more negative reactions to expert attribution, although the backlash is also present for those with higher levels of trust, indicating that other factors likely play a role. We fail to find evidence that individual perceptions or personality traits such as social pressure, altruism or reactance contribute to the backlash. Beyond individual characteristics, we find that the backlash is stronger in countries that exhibited a more stringent government response to the pandemic. JEL Codes: I1, I3, H4
6.
Aidt, T. S., Albornoz, F., & Hauk, E. (2024).
To cut or not to cut: Deforestation policy under the shadow of foreign influence
.
Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization
, 227, Article 106712
This article explores the complex interplay between deforestation policies and foreign influence, using a game theoretical model to analyze geopolitical factors influencing forest conservation decisions in countries with significant rainforests. The model highlights the conflicting interests of foreign powers – one aiming for economic benefits from agriculture and the other advocating for forest preservation to protect environmental services. The paper demonstrates how domestic political dynamics and economic shocks from the international economic influence regulatory decisions on deforestation in the shadow of foreign influence. This understanding is crucial for formulating strategies that balance developmental needs and global environmental concerns.
7.
Hinnosaar, T. (2023).
Optimal Sequential Contests
.
Theoretical Economics
,
I study sequential contests where the efforts of earlier players may be disclosed to later players by nature or by design. The model has many applications, including rent seeking, R\\\&D, oligopoly, public goods provision, and tragedy of the commons. I show that information about other players' efforts increases the total effort. Thus, the total effort is maximized with full transparency and minimized with no transparency. I also show that in addition to the first-mover advantage, there is an earlier-mover advantage. Finally, I derive the limits for large contests and discuss the limit to perfectly competitive outcomes under different disclosure rules.
8.
Burdea, V., Montero, M., & Sefton, M. (2023).
Communication with Partially Verifiable Information: An Experiment
.
Games and Economic Behavior
,
We use laboratory experiments to study communication games with partially verifiable information. In these games, based on Glazer and Rubinstein (2004, 2006), an informed sender sends a two-dimensional message to a receiver, but only one dimension of the message can be verified. We investigate the effect of evidence and verification control using three treatments: one where messages are unverifiable, one where the receiver chooses which dimension to verify and one where the sender has this verification control. First, we find that evidence helps the receiver. Second, despite significant differences in behavior across the two verification treatments, receivers’ payoffs do not differ significantly across these treatments, suggesting they are not hurt by delegating verification control. We also show that a theoretically optimal receiver commitment strategy identified by Glazer and Rubinstein is close to being an optimal response to senders’ observed behavior in both treatments.
9.
Montero, M., & Possajennikov, A. (2023). “Greedy” demand adjustment in cooperative games.
Annals of Operations Research
, https://doi.org/10.1007/s10479-023-05179-8
This paper studies a simple process of demand adjustment in cooperative games. In the process, a randomly chosen player makes the highest possible demand subject to the demands of other coalition members being satisfied. This process converges to the aspiration set; in convex games, this implies convergence to the core. We further introduce perturbations into the process, where players sometimes make a higher demand than feasible. These perturbations make the set of separating aspirations, i.e., demand vectors in which no player is indispensable in order for other players to achieve their demands, the one most resistant to mutations. We fully analyze this process for 3-player games. We further look at weighted majority games with two types of players. In these games, if the coalition of all small players is winning, the process converges to the unique separating aspiration; otherwise, there are many separating aspirations and the process reaches a neighbourhood of a separating aspiration.
10.
Montero, M. (2023).
Bargaining in Legislatures: A New Donation Paradox
. In S. Kurz, N. Maaser, & A. Mayer (Eds.), Advances in Collective Decision Making: Interdisciplinary Perspectives for the 21st Century (159-171). Springer. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-031-21696-1_10
It is well known that being the proposer or agenda setter is advantagenous in many collective decision making situations. In the canonical model of distributive bargaining (Baron and Ferejon, 1989), proposers are certain of being part of the coalition that forms, and, conditional on being in the coalition, a player receives more as a proposer than as a coalition partner. In this paper I show that it is possible for a party to donate part of its proposing probability to another party and be better off as a result. This appears paradoxical, even more so since the recipient never includes the donor in its proposals. The example shows that, even though actually being selected to propose is always valuable ex post, having a higher probability of being proposer may be harmful.
1..10 11..20 21..30 31..40 41..50 51..60 61..70 71..80 81..86

Filter results by:

Journal: American Economic Review (2), Review of Economic Studies (3), Review of Economics and Statistics, Management Science, Journal of Political Economy, Journal of Public Economics, Journal of Economic Literature, Journal of the European Economic Association (4), Economic Journal (2), Journal of Economic Theory (5), Journal of International Economics (2), Economics Letters (2), Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization (5), Games and Economic Behavior (5), Journal of Banking and Finance, European Economic Review (2), Annals of Operations Research (2), Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, American Economic Journal: Microeconomics (2), Economic Theory (2), Economics of Education Review (2), International Economic Review, RAND Journal of Economics (3), Environmental and Resource Economics, International Journal of Industrial Organization, Journal of Economic Psychology, Theoretical Economics, Journal of Corporate Finance, Journal of Industrial Economics, Scandinavian Journal of Economics, Theory and Decision (2), Journal of Comparative Economics, Resource and Energy Economics (2), International Journal of Game Theory, Oxford Economic Papers, Quarterly Journal of Political Science, Journal of Public Economic Theory, Mathematical Social Sciences (2), International Journal of Finance and Economics, Environmental Economics and Policy Studies (2), Brain Communications, Dynamic Games and Applications, Games (2),

Year: 2024 (6), 2023 (13), 2022 (5), 2021 (7), 2020 (6), 2019 (5), 2018 (13), 2017 (11), 2016 (9), 2015 (11)